The West Virginia-specific report identifies our state as having higher than average energy consumption, especially in the industrial sector. While the state has 0.6 % of the US population, it uses 0.8 % of the energy to produce only 0.4 % of the GDP. Energy efficiency policies could save 900 million dollars for state residents, and help create 5000 new jobs by 2020 (compared to 70,000 unemployed at the end of 2009).
Read the report. This is important information to have at your …
[View More]fingertips.
JBK
>>> Paula Carrell <Paula.Carrell(a)sierraclub.org> 4/15/2010 3:55 PM >>>
Apologies for duplication, but I wanted to be certain that all of you -- and your Energy leadership -- saw this.
Lots of information here -- sections specific to each state.
http://www.seealliance.org/programs/se-efficiency-study.php
[View Less]
----- Original Message -----
From: DSGJr(a)aol.com
To: deniseap(a)earthlink.net ; jbc329(a)earthlink.net ; lesleemac(a)frontiernet.net
Cc: jkotcon(a)wvu.edu ; fyoung(a)mountain.net
Sent: Friday, April 16, 2010 11:10 AM
Subject: Selenium News Flash . . .
Just got interviewed by Erica Peterson (WV Public Broadcasting) who tells me that EPA has sent letters to every WV mine that requested more time to meet selenium compliance schedule under the bill passed by the Legislature in 2009 -- EPA …
[View More]is denying their requests.
So, note to the Legislature: WE TOLD YOU SO!!
don
[View Less]
>>> "Diggins, Molly" molly.diggins(a)SIERRACLUB.ORG> 4/12/2010 1:38 PM >> ( mailto:molly.diggins@SIERRACLUB.ORG> )
FYI, attached is a report and fact sheet on coal ash issued today by the North Carolina Chapter. It focuses on the largely untold story of problems with structural fill for land development. My guess is that similar problems exist across the country.
Early press: http://www.charlotteobserver.com/2010/04/12/1371555/report-nc-ignores-coal-…
Molly
--
…
[View More]Molly Diggins
State Director
NC Sierra Club
(p) 919.833.8467
(e) molly.diggins(a)sierraclub.org
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - To unsubscribe from the CONS-FRED list, send any message to: CONS-FRED-signoff-request(a)LISTS.SIERRACLUB.ORG Check out our Listserv Lists support site for more information: http://www.sierraclub.org/lists/faq.asp To view the Sierra Club List Terms & Conditions, see: http://www.sierraclub.org/lists/terms.asp
[View Less]
Below is a story on what the North Carolina Chapter is doing on fly ash. I recently received a proposal from DownStream strategies for a similar study in West Virginia, focusing on the counties around Morgantown where ash dumping is greatest. It would likely be several thousands of dollars, but this may be a useful way to build on the actions elsewhere.
Is the WV Chapter interested in doing something like this?
JBK
>>> Paula Carrell Paula.Carrell(a)sierraclub.org> 4/12/2010 1:…
[View More]50 PM >> ( mailto:Paula.Carrell@sierraclub.org> )
This is my favorite part of the below article:
-State officials haven't yet drafted recommended changes. But Crissman said the Sierra Club's recommendations - that ash be dumped only in lined landfills, groundwater monitoring be required at disposal sites and developers held accountable for contamination clean-ups - "look pretty good."
----- Forwarded by Paula Carrell/Sierraclub on 04/12/2010 10:49 AM -----
Report: N.C. ignores coal ash threat
Sierra Club says ash used as construction fill endangers water.
By Bruce Henderson
bhenderson(a)charlotteobserver.com
Posted: Monday, Apr. 12, 2010
The state largely ignores millions of tons of ash from coal-fired power plants that threatens to contaminate N.C. groundwater, lakes and streams, the N.C. Sierra Club says in a report today.
Coal ash has gotten increased scrutiny since a massive spill of ash sludge in Tennessee in late 2008. Ash contains potentially toxic metals such as arsenic, cadmium and mercury.
The Sierra report, like an Observer article in December, focuses on the use of dry ash to fill gullies and prepare roadbeds and building sites. More than 800,000 tons of ash was used for so-called structural fill statewide last year, the report says.
Those sites don't have to be lined to keep toxic material out of groundwater and aren't regularly checked to find whether they're tainting water. Property deeds often don't show that ash has been dumped, as state law requires.
Ash is known to have contaminated water in Robeson, Nash and Northampton counties, according to state records, the report said. More often, it said, no one looks for contamination.
"Wherever the state has looked, there have been problems for the most part," said Molly Diggins, the Sierra Club's state director.
"The data is thin because there are no regular inspections or reporting. It's hard to get a full understanding when you don't have a full perspective of potential problems."
Mecklenburg, Cabarrus, Catawba, Gaston, Iredell and Rowan are among 20 N.C. counties with structural fill, records show. Iredell has 17 sites, more than any other county, the report said.
State scrutiny has increased in recent months, the report says, with violations found at 28 of the 48 sites inspected. Most violations cited a lack of vegetation or soil cover over the ash.
Paul Crissman, chief of the state's solid waste section, said his staff first recognized the need for more oversight of structural fill sites since it began finding violations in the mid-1990s.
"It led to our being convinced that the Sierra Club is correct and that we need to make new regulations," he said.
State officials haven't yet drafted recommended changes. But Crissman said the Sierra Club's recommendations - that ash be dumped only in lined landfills, groundwater monitoring be required at disposal sites and developers held accountable for contamination clean-ups - "look pretty good."
A key question in light of state budget problems, he said, is how to pay for additional oversight.
The Sierra Club views ash as a further indictment of coal-fired power plants, which it believes should be phased out.
Duke Energy says it stopped using ash for structural fill in 2003. Limiting disposal to lined landfills would stop the use of ash in making concrete and cement products, it says, effectively doubling the amount that has to be disposed.
"We would support discussions on additional groundwater monitoring for an entire coal-fired power plant site which would encompass on-site ash basins, landfills and structural fills," Duke said in a statement.
The Environmental Protection Agency is weighing tougher coal-ash regulations, including whether to label ash as hazardous waste. That designation would be expected to greatly increase oversight and disposal costs.
Subscribe to The Charlotte Observer & Earn Miles. - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
[View Less]
Excellent commentary on the economics of climate change. This is long,
but it ought to be required reading by anyone on the Energy Committee.
I especially like the point about Ronald Reagan's faith in the "miracle
of the marketplace" and the loss of faith by those who claim greenhouse
gas controls will bankrupt America. We need to confront the
obstructionists with optimism and the appeal to future generations.
JBK
>>> "William V. DePaulo, Esq." <william.depaulo(a)gmail.com…
[View More]> 4/13/2010
8:28 AM >>>
April 5, 2010
Building a Green EconomyBy PAUL KRUGMAN (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/opinion/editorialsandoped/oped/columnists/pau…
)
If you listen to climate scientists — and despite the relentless
campaign to discredit their work, you should — it is long past time to
do something about emissions of carbon dioxide and other greenhouse
gases. If we continue with business as usual, they say, we are facing a
rise in global temperatures that will be little short of apocalyptic.
And to avoid that apocalypse, we have to wean our economy from the use
of fossil fuels, coal above all.
But is it possible to make drastic cuts in greenhouse-gas emissions
without destroying our economy?
Like the debate over climate change (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/news/science/topics/globalwarming/index.html?…
) itself, the debate over climate economics looks very different from
the inside than it often does in popular media. The casual reader might
have the impression that there are real doubts about whether emissions
can be reduced without inflicting severe damage on the economy. In fact,
once you filter out the noise generated by special-interest groups, you
discover that there is widespread agreement among environmental
economists that a market-based program to deal with the threat of
climate change — one that limits carbon emissions by putting a price on
them — can achieve large results at modest, though not trivial, cost.
There is, however, much less agreement on how fast we should move,
whether major conservation efforts should start almost immediately or be
gradually increased over the course of many decades.
In what follows, I will offer a brief survey of the economics of
climate change or, more precisely, the economics of lessening climate
change. I’ll try to lay out the areas of broad agreement as well as
those that remain in major dispute. First, though, a primer in the basic
economics of environmental protection.
Environmental Econ 101
If there’s a single central insight in economics, it’s this: There are
mutual gains from transactions between consenting adults. If the going
price of widgets is $10 and I buy a widget, it must be because that
widget is worth more than $10 to me. If you sell a widget at that price,
it must be because it costs you less than $10 to make it. So buying and
selling in the widget market works to the benefit of both buyers and
sellers. More than that, some careful analysis shows that if there is
effective competition in the widget market, so that the price ends up
matching the number of widgets people want to buy to the number of
widgets other people want to sell, the outcome is to maximize the total
gains to producers and consumers. Free markets are “efficient” — which,
in economics-speak as opposed to plain English, means that nobody can be
made better off without making someone else worse off.
Now, efficiency isn’t everything. In particular, there is no reason to
assume that free markets will deliver an outcome that we consider fair
or just. So the case for market efficiency says nothing about whether we
should have, say, some form of guaranteed health insurance, aid to the
poor and so forth. But the logic of basic economics says that we should
try to achieve social goals through “aftermarket” interventions. That
is, we should let markets do their job, making efficient use of the
nation’s resources, then utilize taxes and transfers to help those whom
the market passes by.
But what if a deal between consenting adults imposes costs on people
who are not part of the exchange? What if you manufacture a widget and I
buy it, to our mutual benefit, but the process of producing that widget
involves dumping toxic sludge into other people’s drinking water? When
there are “negative externalities” — costs that economic actors impose
on others without paying a price for their actions — any presumption
that the market economy, left to its own devices, will do the right
thing goes out the window. So what should we do? Environmental economics
is all about answering that question.
One way to deal with negative externalities is to make rules that
prohibit or at least limit behavior that imposes especially high costs
on others. That’s what we did in the first major wave of environmental
legislation in the early 1970s: cars were required to meet emission
standards for the chemicals that cause smog, factories were required to
limit the volume of effluent they dumped into waterways and so on. And
this approach yielded results; America’s air and water became a lot
cleaner in the decades that followed.
But while the direct regulation of activities that cause pollution
makes sense in some cases, it is seriously defective in others, because
it does not offer any scope for flexibility and creativity. Consider the
biggest environmental issue of the 1980s — acid rain. Emissions of
sulfur dioxide from power plants, it turned out, tend to combine with
water downwind and produce flora- and wildlife-destroying sulfuric acid.
In 1977, the government made its first stab at confronting the issue,
recommending that all new coal-fired plants have scrubbers to remove
sulfur dioxide from their emissions. Imposing a tough standard on all
plants was problematic, because retrofitting some older plants would
have been extremely expensive. By regulating only new plants, however,
the government passed up the opportunity to achieve fairly cheap
pollution control at plants that were, in fact, easy to retrofit. Short
of a de facto federal takeover of the power industry, with federal
officials issuing specific instructions to each plant, how was this
conundrum to be resolved?
Enter Arthur Cecil Pigou, an early-20th-century British don, whose 1920
book, “The Economics of Welfare,” is generally regarded as the ur-text
of environmental economics.
Somewhat surprisingly, given his current status as a godfather of
economically sophisticated environmentalism, Pigou didn’t actually
stress the problem of pollution. Rather than focusing on, say, London’s
famous fog (actually acrid smog, caused by millions of coal fires), he
opened his discussion with an example that must have seemed twee even in
1920, a hypothetical case in which “the game-preserving activities of
one occupier involve the overrunning of a neighboring occupier’s land by
rabbits.” But never mind. What Pigou enunciated was a principle:
economic activities that impose unrequited costs on other people should
not always be banned, but they should be discouraged. And the right way
to curb an activity, in most cases, is to put a price on it. So Pigou
proposed that people who generate negative externalities should have to
pay a fee reflecting the costs they impose on others — what has come to
be known as a Pigovian tax. The simplest version of a Pigovian tax is an
effluent fee: anyone who dumps pollutants into a river, or emits them
into the air, must pay a sum proportional to the amount dumped.
Pigou’s analysis lay mostly fallow for almost half a century, as
economists spent their time grappling with issues that seemed more
pressing, like the Great Depression (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/subjects/g/great_depres…
). But with the rise of environmental regulation, economists dusted off
Pigou and began pressing for a “market-based” approach that gives the
private sector an incentive, via prices, to limit pollution, as opposed
to a “command and control” fix that issues specific instructions in the
form of regulations.
The initial reaction by many environmental activists to this idea was
hostile, largely on moral grounds. Pollution, they felt, should be
treated like a crime rather than something you have the right to do as
long as you pay enough money. Moral concerns aside, there was also
considerable skepticism about whether market incentives would actually
be successful in reducing pollution. Even today, Pigovian taxes as
originally envisaged are relatively rare. The most successful example
I’ve been able to find is a Dutch tax on discharges of water
containing organic materials.
What has caught on instead is a variant that most economists consider
more or less equivalent: a system of tradable emissions permits, a k a
cap and trade (
http://topics.nytimes.com/topics/reference/timestopics/subjects/g/greenhous…
). In this model, a limited number of licenses to emit a specified
pollutant, like sulfur dioxide, are issued. A business that wants to
create more pollution than it is licensed for can go out and buy
additional licenses from other parties; a firm that has more licenses
than it intends to use can sell its surplus. This gives everyone an
incentive to reduce pollution, because buyers would not have to acquire
as many licenses if they can cut back on their emissions, and sellers
can unload more licenses if they do the same. In fact, economically, a
cap-and-trade system produces the same incentives to reduce pollution as
a Pigovian tax, with the price of licenses effectively serving as a tax
on pollution.
In practice there are a couple of important differences between cap and
trade and a pollution tax. One is that the two systems produce different
types of uncertainty. If the government imposes a pollution tax,
polluters know what price they will have to pay, but the government does
not know how much pollution they will generate. If the government
imposes a cap, it knows the amount of pollution, but polluters do not
know what the price of emissions will be. Another important difference
has to do with government revenue. A pollution tax is, well, a tax,
which imposes costs on the private sector while generating revenue for
the government. Cap and trade is a bit more complicated. If the
government simply auctions off licenses and collects the revenue, then
it is just like a tax. Cap and trade, however, often involves handing
out licenses to existing players, so the potential revenue goes to
industry instead of the government.
Politically speaking, doling out licenses to industry isn’t entirely
bad, because it offers a way to partly compensate some of the groups
whose interests would suffer if a serious climate-change policy were
adopted. This can make passing legislation more feasible.
These political considerations probably explain why the solution to the
acid-rain predicament took the form of cap and trade and why licenses to
pollute were distributed free to power companies. It’s also worth noting
that the Waxman-Markey bill, a cap-and-trade setup for greenhouse gases
that starts by giving out many licenses to industry but puts up a
growing number for auction in later years, was actually passed by the
House of Representatives last year; it’s hard to imagine a broad-based
emissions tax doing the same for many years.
That’s not to say that emission taxes are a complete nonstarter. Some
senators have recently floated a proposal for a sort of hybrid solution,
with cap and trade for some parts of the economy and carbon taxes for
others — mainly oil and gas. The political logic seems to be that the
oil industry thinks consumers won’t blame it for higher gas prices if
those prices reflect an explicit tax.
In any case, experience suggests that market-based emission controls
work. Our recent history with acid rain shows as much. The Clean Air Act
(
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/subjects/c/clean_air_ac…
) of 1990 introduced a cap-and-trade system in which power plants could
buy and sell the right to emit sulfur dioxide, leaving it up to
individual companies to manage their own business within the new limits.
Sure enough, over time sulfur-dioxide emissions from power plants were
cut almost in half, at a much lower cost than even optimists expected;
electricity prices fell instead of rising. Acid rain did not disappear
as a problem, but it was significantly mitigated. The results, it would
seem, demonstrated that we can deal with environmental problems when we
have to.
So there we have it, right? The emission of carbon dioxide and other
greenhouse gases is a classic negative externality — the “biggest market
failure the world has ever seen,” in the words of Nicholas Stern, the
author of a report on the subject for the British government. Textbook
economics and real-world experience tell us that we should have policies
to discourage activities that generate negative externalities and that
it is generally best to rely on a market-based approach.
Climate of Doubt?
This is an article on climate economics, not climate science. But
before we get to the economics, it’s worth establishing three things
about the state of the scientific debate.
The first is that the planet is indeed warming. Weather fluctuates, and
as a consequence it’s easy enough to point to an unusually warm year in
the recent past, note that it’s cooler now and claim, “See, the planet
is getting cooler, not warmer!” But if you look at the evidence the
right way — taking averages over periods long enough to smooth out the
fluctuations — the upward trend is unmistakable: each successive decade
since the 1970s has been warmer than the one before.
Second, climate models predicted this well in advance, even getting the
magnitude of the temperature rise roughly right. While it’s relatively
easy to cook up an analysis that matches known data, it is much harder
to create a model that accurately forecasts the future. So the fact that
climate modelers more than 20 years ago successfully predicted the
subsequent global warming gives them enormous credibility.
Yet that’s not the conclusion you might draw from the many media
reports that have focused on matters like hacked e-mail and climate
scientists’ talking about a “trick” to “hide” an anomalous decline in
one data series or expressing their wish to see papers by climate
skeptics kept out of research reviews. The truth, however, is that the
supposed scandals evaporate on closer examination, revealing only that
climate researchers are human beings, too. Yes, scientists try to make
their results stand out, but no data were suppressed. Yes, scientists
dislike it when work that they think deliberately obfuscates the issues
gets published. What else is new? Nothing suggests that there should not
continue to be strong support for climate research.
And this brings me to my third point: models based on this research
indicate that if we continue adding greenhouse gases to the atmosphere
as we have, we will eventually face drastic changes in the climate.
Let’s be clear. We’re not talking about a few more hot days in the
summer and a bit less snow in the winter; we’re talking about massively
disruptive events, like the transformation of the Southwestern United
States into a permanent dust bowl over the next few decades.
Now, despite the high credibility of climate modelers, there is still
tremendous uncertainty in their long-term forecasts. But as we will see
shortly, uncertainty makes the case for action stronger, not weaker. So
climate change demands action. Is a cap-and-trade program along the
lines of the model used to reduce sulfur dioxide the right way to go?
Serious opposition to cap and trade generally comes in two forms: an
argument that more direct action — in particular, a ban on coal-fired
power plants — would be more effective and an argument that an emissions
tax would be better than emissions trading. (Let’s leave aside those who
dismiss climate science altogether and oppose any limits on
greenhouse-gas emissions, as well as those who oppose the use of any
kind of market-based remedy.) There’s something to each of these
positions, just not as much as their proponents think.
When it comes to direct action, you can make the case that economists
love markets not wisely but too well, that they are too ready to assume
that changing people’s financial incentives fixes every problem. In
particular, you can’t put a price on something unless you can measure it
accurately, and that can be both difficult and expensive. So sometimes
it’s better simply to lay down some basic rules about what people can
and cannot do.
Consider auto emissions, for example. Could we or should we charge each
car owner a fee proportional to the emissions from his or her tailpipe?
Surely not. You would have to install expensive monitoring equipment on
every car, and you would also have to worry about fraud. It’s almost
certainly better to do what we actually do, which is impose emissions
standards on all cars.
Is there a comparable argument to be made for greenhouse-gas emissions?
My initial reaction, which I suspect most economists would share, is
that the very scale and complexity of the situation requires a
market-based solution, whether cap and trade or an emissions tax. After
all, greenhouse gases are a direct or indirect byproduct of almost
everything produced in a modern economy, from the houses we live in to
the cars we drive. Reducing emissions of those gases will require
getting people to change their behavior in many different ways, some of
them impossible to identify until we have a much better grasp of green
technology. So can we really make meaningful progress by telling people
specifically what will or will not be permitted? Econ 101 tells us —
probably correctly — that the only way to get people to change their
behavior appropriately is to put a price on emissions so this cost in
turn gets incorporated into everything else in a way that reflects
ultimate environmental impacts.
When shoppers go to the grocery store, for example, they will find that
fruits and vegetables from farther away have higher prices than local
produce, reflecting in part the cost of emission licenses or taxes paid
to ship that produce. When businesses decide how much to spend on
insulation, they will take into account the costs of heating and
air-conditioning that include the price of emissions licenses or taxes
for electricity generation. When electric utilities have to choose among
energy sources, they will have to take into account the higher license
fees or taxes associated with fossil-fuel consumption. And so on down
the line. A market-based system would create decentralized incentives to
do the right thing, and that’s the only way it can be done.
That said, some specific rules may be required. James Hansen (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/people/h/james_e_hansen…
), the renowned climate scientist who deserves much of the credit for
making global warming an issue in the first place, has argued forcefully
that most of the climate-change problem comes down to just one thing,
burning coal, and that whatever else we do, we have to shut down coal
burning over the next couple decades. My economist’s reaction is that a
stiff license fee would strongly discourage coal use anyway. But a
market-based system might turn out to have loopholes — and their
consequences could be dire. So I would advocate supplementing
market-based disincentives with direct controls on coal burning.
What about the case for an emissions tax rather than cap and trade?
There’s no question that a straightforward tax would have many
advantages over legislation like Waxman-Markey, which is full of
exceptions and special situations. But that’s not really a useful
comparison: of course an idealized emissions tax looks better than a
cap-and-trade system that has already passed the House with all its
attendant compromises. The question is whether the emissions tax that
could actually be put in place is better than cap and trade. There is no
reason to believe that it would be — indeed, there is no reason to
believe that a broad-based emissions tax would make it through
Congress.
To be fair, Hansen has made an interesting moral argument against cap
and trade, one that’s much more sophisticated than the old view that
it’s wrong to let polluters buy the right to pollute. What Hansen
draws attention to is the fact that in a cap-and-trade world, acts of
individual virtue do not contribute to social goals. If you choose to
drive a hybrid car or buy a house with a small carbon footprint, all you
are doing is freeing up emissions permits for someone else, which means
that you have done nothing to reduce the threat of climate change. He
has a point. But altruism cannot effectively deal with climate change.
Any serious solution must rely mainly on creating a system that gives
everyone a self-interested reason to produce fewer emissions. It’s a
shame, but climate altruism must take a back seat to the task of getting
such a system in place.
The bottom line, then, is that while climate change may be a vastly
bigger problem than acid rain, the logic of how to respond to it is much
the same. What we need are market incentives for reducing greenhouse-gas
emissions — along with some direct controls over coal use — and cap and
trade is a reasonable way to create those incentives.
But can we afford to do that? Equally important, can we afford not to?
The Cost of Action
Just as there is a rough consensus among climate modelers about the
likely trajectory of temperatures if we do not act to cut the emissions
of greenhouse gases, there is a rough consensus among economic modelers
about the costs of action. That general opinion may be summed up as
follows: Restricting emissions would slow economic growth — but not by
much. The Congressional Budget Office (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/organizations/c/congres…
), relying on a survey of models, has concluded that Waxman-Markey
“would reduce the projected average annual rate of growth of gross
domestic product (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/subjects/u/united_state…
) between 2010 and 2050 by 0.03 to 0.09 percentage points.” That is, it
would trim average annual growth to 2.31 percent, at worst, from 2.4
percent. Over all, the Budget Office concludes, strong climate-change
policy would leave the American economy between 1.1 percent and 3.4
percent smaller in 2050 than it would be otherwise.
And what about the world economy? In general, modelers tend to find
that climate-change policies would lower global output by a somewhat
smaller percentage than the comparable figures for the United States.
The main reason is that emerging economies like China currently use
energy fairly inefficiently, partly as a result of national policies
that have kept the prices of fossil fuels very low, and could thus
achieve large energy savings at a modest cost. One recent review of the
available estimates put the costs of a very strong climate policy —
substantially more aggressive than contemplated in current legislative
proposals — at between 1 and 3 percent of gross world product.
Such figures typically come from a model that combines all sorts of
engineering and marketplace estimates. These will include, for instance,
engineers’ best calculations of how much it costs to generate
electricity in various ways, from coal, gas and nuclear and solar power
(
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/news/science/topics/solar_energy/index.html?i…
) at given resource prices. Then estimates will be made, based on
historical experience, of how much consumers would cut back their
electricity consumption if its price rises. The same process is followed
for other kinds of energy, like motor fuel. And the model assumes that
everyone makes the best choice given the economic environment — that
power generators choose the least expensive means of producing
electricity, while consumers conserve energy as long as the money saved
by buying less electricity exceeds the cost of using less power in the
form either of other spending or loss of convenience. After all this
analysis, it’s possible to predict how producers and consumers of energy
will react to policies that put a price on emissions and how much those
reactions will end up costing the economy as a whole.
There are, of course, a number of ways this kind of modeling could be
wrong. Many of the underlying estimates are necessarily somewhat
speculative; nobody really knows, for instance, what solar power will
cost once it finally becomes a large-scale proposition. There is also
reason to doubt the assumption that people actually make the right
choices: many studies have found that consumers fail to take measures to
conserve energy, like improving insulation, even when they could save
money by doing so.
But while it’s unlikely that these models get everything right, it’s a
good bet that they overstate rather than understate the economic costs
of climate-change action. That is what the experience from the
cap-and-trade program for acid rain suggests: costs came in well below
initial predictions. And in general, what the models do not and cannot
take into account is creativity; surely, faced with an economy in which
there are big monetary payoffs for reducing greenhouse-gas emissions,
the private sector will come up with ways to limit emissions that are
not yet in any model.
What you hear from conservative opponents of a climate-change policy,
however, is that any attempt to limit emissions would be economically
devastating. The Heritage Foundation (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/organizations/h/heritag…
), for one, responded to Budget Office estimates on Waxman-Markey with a
broadside titled, “C.B.O. Grossly Underestimates Costs of Cap and Trade.”
The real effects, the foundation said, would be ruinous for families and
job creation.
This reaction — this extreme pessimism about the economy’s ability to
live with cap and trade — is very much at odds with typical conservative
rhetoric. After all, modern conservatives express a deep, almost
mystical confidence in the effectiveness of market incentives — Ronald
Reagan (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/people/r/ronald_wilson_…
) liked to talk about the “magic of the marketplace.” They believe that
the capitalist system can deal with all kinds of limitations, that
technology, say, can easily overcome any constraints on growth posed by
limited reserves of oil or other natural resources. And yet now they
submit that this same private sector is utterly incapable of coping with
a limit on overall emissions, even though such a cap would, from the
private sector’s point of view, operate very much like a limited supply
of a resource, like land. Why don’t they believe that the dynamism of
capitalism will spur it to find ways to make do in a world of reduced
carbon emissions? Why do they think the marketplace loses its magic as
soon as market incentives are invoked in favor of conservation?
Clearly, conservatives abandon all faith in the ability of markets to
cope with climate-change policy because they don’t want government
intervention. Their stated pessimism about the cost of climate policy is
essentially a political ploy rather than a reasoned economic judgment.
The giveaway is the strong tendency of conservative opponents of cap and
trade to argue in bad faith. That Heritage Foundation broadside accuses
the Congressional Budget Office of making elementary logical errors, but
if you actually read the office’s report, it’s clear that the foundation
is willfully misreading it. Conservative politicians have been even more
shameless. The National Republican Congressional Committee, for example,
issued multiple press releases specifically citing a study from M.I.T. (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/organizations/m/massach…
) as the basis for a claim that cap and trade would cost $3,100 per
household, despite repeated attempts by the study’s authors to get out
the word that the actual number was only about a quarter as much.
The truth is that there is no credible research suggesting that taking
strong action on climate change is beyond the economy’s capacity. Even
if you do not fully trust the models — and you shouldn’t — history and
logic both suggest that the models are overestimating, not
underestimating, the costs of climate action. We can afford to do
something about climate change.
But that’s not the same as saying we should. Action will have costs,
and these must be compared with the costs of not acting. Before I get to
that, however, let me touch on an issue that will become central if we
actually do get moving on climate policy: how to get the rest of the
world to go along with us.
The China Syndrome
The United States is still the world’s largest economy, which makes the
country one of the world’s largest sources of greenhouse gases. But it’s
not the largest. China, which burns much more coal per dollar of gross
domestic product than the United States does, overtook us by that
measure around three years ago. Over all, the advanced countries — the
rich man’s club comprising Europe, North America and Japan — account for
only about half of greenhouse emissions, and that’s a fraction that will
fall over time. In short, there can’t be a solution to climate change
unless the rest of the world, emerging economies in particular,
participates in a major way.
Inevitably those who resist tackling climate change point to the global
nature of emissions as a reason not to act. Emissions limits in America
won’t accomplish much, they argue, if China and others don’t match our
effort. And they highlight China’s obduracy in the Copenhagen
negotiations as evidence that other countries will not cooperate.
Indeed, emerging economies feel that they have a right to emit freely
without worrying about the consequences — that’s what today’s rich
countries got to do for two centuries. It’s just not possible to get
global cooperation on climate change, goes the argument, and that means
there is no point in taking any action at all.
For those who think that taking action is essential, the right question
is how to persuade China and other emerging nations to participate in
emissions limits. Carrots, or positive inducements, are one answer.
Imagine setting up cap-and-trade systems in China and the United States —
but allow international trading in permits, so Chinese and American
companies can trade emission rights. By setting overall caps at levels
designed to ensure that China sells us a substantial number of permits,
we would in effect be paying China to cut its emissions. Since the
evidence suggests that the cost of cutting emissions would be lower in
China than in the United States, this could be a good deal for
everyone.
But what if the Chinese (or the Indians or the Brazilians, etc.) do not
want to participate in such a system? Then you need sticks as well as
carrots. In particular, you need carbon tariffs.
A carbon tariff would be a tax levied on imported goods proportional to
the carbon emitted in the manufacture of those goods. Suppose that China
refuses to reduce emissions, while the United States adopts policies
that set a price of $100 per ton of carbon emissions. If the United
States were to impose such a carbon tariff, any shipment to America of
Chinese goods whose production involved emitting a ton of carbon would
result in a $100 tax over and above any other duties. Such tariffs, if
levied by major players — probably the United States and the European
Union (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/organizations/e/europea…
) — would give noncooperating countries a strong incentive to reconsider
their positions.
To the objection that such a policy would be protectionist (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/subjects/p/protectionis…
), a violation of the principles of free trade, one reply is, So?
Keeping world markets open is important, but avoiding planetary
catastrophe is a lot more important. In any case, however, you can argue
that carbon tariffs are well within the rules of normal trade relations.
As long as the tariff imposed on the carbon content of imports is
comparable to the cost of domestic carbon licenses, the effect is to
charge your own consumers a price that reflects the carbon emitted in
what they buy, no matter where it is produced. That should be legal
under international-trading rules. In fact, even the World Trade
Organization (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/organizations/w/world_t…
), which is charged with policing trade policies, has published a study
suggesting that carbon tariffs would pass muster.
Needless to say, the actual business of getting cooperative, worldwide
action on climate change would be much more complicated and tendentious
than this discussion suggests. Yet the problem is not as intractable as
you often hear. If the United States and Europe decide to move on
climate policy, they almost certainly would be able to cajole and chivvy
the rest of the world into joining the effort. We can do this.
The Costs of Inaction
In public discussion, the climate-change skeptics have clearly been
gaining ground over the past couple of years, even though the odds have
been looking good lately that 2010 could be the warmest year on record.
But climate modelers themselves have grown increasingly pessimistic.
What were previously worst-case scenarios have become base-line
projections, with a number of organizations doubling their predictions
for temperature rise over the course of the 21st century. Underlying
this new pessimism is increased concern about feedback effects — for
example, the release of methane, a significant greenhouse gas, from
seabeds and tundra as the planet warms.
At this point, the projections of climate change, assuming we continue
business as usual, cluster around an estimate that average temperatures
will be about 9 degrees Fahrenheit higher in 2100 than they were in
2000. That’s a lot — equivalent to the difference in average
temperatures between New York and central Mississippi. Such a huge
change would have to be highly disruptive. And the troubles would not
stop there: temperatures would continue to rise.
Furthermore, changes in average temperature will by no means be the
whole story. Precipitation patterns will change, with some regions
getting much wetter and others much drier. Many modelers also predict
more intense storms. Sea levels would rise, with the impact intensified
by those storms: coastal flooding, already a major source of natural
disasters, would become much more frequent and severe. And there might
be drastic changes in the climate of some regions as ocean currents
shift. It’s always worth bearing in mind that London is at the same
latitude as Labrador; without the Gulf Stream, Western Europe would be
barely habitable.
While there may be some benefits from a warmer climate, it seems almost
certain that upheaval on this scale would make the United States, and
the world as a whole, poorer than it would be otherwise. How much
poorer? If ours were a preindustrial, primarily agricultural society,
extreme climate change would be obviously catastrophic. But we have an
advanced economy, the kind that has historically shown great ability to
adapt to changed circumstances. If this sounds similar to my argument
that the costs of emissions limits would be tolerable, it ought to: the
same flexibility that should enable us to deal with a much higher carbon
prices should also help us cope with a somewhat higher average
temperature.
But there are at least two reasons to take sanguine assessments of the
consequences of climate change with a grain of salt. One is that, as I
have just pointed out, it’s not just a matter of having warmer weather —
many of the costs of climate change are likely to result from droughts,
flooding and severe storms. The other is that while modern economies may
be highly adaptable, the same may not be true of ecosystems. The last
time the earth experienced warming at anything like the pace we now
expect was during the Paleocene-Eocene Thermal Maximum, about 55 million
years ago, when temperatures rose by about 11 degrees Fahrenheit over
the course of around 20,000 years (which is a much slower rate than the
current pace of warming). That increase was associated with mass
extinctions, which, to put it mildly, probably would not be good for
living standards.
So how can we put a price tag on the effects of global warming? The
most widely quoted estimates, like those in the Dynamic Integrated Model
of Climate and the Economy, known as DICE, used by Yale’s William
Nordhaus and colleagues, depend upon educated guesswork to place a value
on the negative effects of global warming in a number of crucial areas,
especially agriculture and coastal protection, then try to make some
allowance for other possible repercussions. Nordhaus has argued that a
global temperature rise of 4.5 degrees Fahrenheit — which used to be the
consensus projection for 2100 — would reduce gross world product by a
bit less than 2 percent. But what would happen if, as a growing number
of models suggest, the actual temperature rise is twice as great? Nobody
really knows how to make that extrapolation. For what it’s worth,
Nordhaus’s model puts losses from a rise of 9 degrees at about 5 percent
of gross world product. Many critics have argued, however, that the cost
might be much higher.
Despite the uncertainty, it’s tempting to make a direct comparison
between the estimated losses and the estimates of what the mitigation
policies will cost: climate change will lower gross world product by 5
percent, stopping it will cost 2 percent, so let’s go ahead.
Unfortunately the reckoning is not that simple for at least four
reasons.
First, substantial global warming is already “baked in,” as a result of
past emissions and because even with a strong climate-change policy the
amount of carbon dioxide in the atmosphere is most likely to continue
rising for many years. So even if the nations of the world do manage to
take on climate change, we will still have to pay for earlier inaction.
As a result, Nordhaus’s loss estimates may overstate the gains from
action.
Second, the economic costs from emissions limits would start as soon as
the policy went into effect and under most proposals would become
substantial within around 20 years. If we don’t act, meanwhile, the big
costs would probably come late this century (although some things, like
the transformation of the American Southwest into a dust bowl, might
come much sooner). So how you compare those costs depends on how much
you value costs in the distant future relative to costs that materialize
much sooner.
Third, and cutting in the opposite direction, if we don’t take action,
global warming won’t stop in 2100: temperatures, and losses, will
continue to rise. So if you place a significant weight on the really,
really distant future, the case for action is stronger than even the
2100 estimates suggest.
Finally and most important is the matter of uncertainty. We’re
uncertain about the magnitude of climate change, which is inevitable,
because we’re talking about reaching levels of carbon dioxide in the
atmosphere not seen in millions of years. The recent doubling of many
modelers’ predictions for 2100 is itself an illustration of the scope of
that uncertainty; who knows what revisions may occur in the years ahead.
Beyond that, nobody really knows how much damage would result from
temperature rises of the kind now considered likely.
You might think that this uncertainty weakens the case for action, but
it actually strengthens it. As Harvard (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/organizations/h/harvard…
)’s Martin Weitzman has argued in several influential papers, if there
is a significant chance of utter catastrophe, that chance — rather than
what is most likely to happen — should dominate cost-benefit
calculations. And utter catastrophe does look like a realistic
possibility, even if it is not the most likely outcome.
Weitzman argues — and I agree — that this risk of catastrophe, rather
than the details of cost-benefit calculations, makes the most powerful
case for strong climate policy. Current projections of global warming in
the absence of action are just too close to the kinds of numbers
associated with doomsday scenarios. It would be irresponsible — it’s
tempting to say criminally irresponsible — not to step back from what
could all too easily turn out to be the edge of a cliff.
Still that leaves a big debate about the pace of action.
The Ramp Versus the Big Bang
Economists who analyze climate policies agree on some key issues. There
is a broad consensus that we need to put a price on carbon emissions,
that this price must eventually be very high but that the negative
economic effects from this policy will be of manageable size. In other
words, we can and should act to limit climate change. But there is a
ferocious debate among knowledgeable analysts about timing, about how
fast carbon prices should rise to significant levels.
On one side are economists who have been working for many years on
so-called integrated-assessment models, which combine models of climate
change with models of both the damage from global warming and the costs
of cutting emissions. For the most part, the message from these
economists is a sort of climate version of St. Augustine’s famous
prayer, “Give me chastity and continence, but not just now.” Thus
Nordhaus’s DICE model says that the price of carbon emissions should
eventually rise to more than $200 a ton, effectively more than
quadrupling the cost of coal, but that most of that increase should come
late this century, with a much more modest initial fee of around $30 a
ton. Nordhaus calls this recommendation for a policy that builds
gradually over a long period the “climate-policy ramp.”
On the other side are some more recent entrants to the field, who work
with similar models but come to different conclusions. Most famously,
Nicholas Stern, an economist at the London School of Economics, argued
in 2006 for quick, aggressive action to limit emissions, which would
most likely imply much higher carbon prices. This alternative position
doesn’t appear to have a standard name, so let me call it the
“climate-policy big bang.”
I find it easiest to make sense of the arguments by thinking of
policies to reduce carbon emissions as a sort of public investment
project: you pay a price now and derive benefits in the form of a
less-damaged planet later. And by later, I mean much later; today’s
emissions will affect the amount of carbon in the atmosphere decades,
and possibly centuries, into the future. So if you want to assess
whether a given investment in emissions reduction is worth making, you
have to estimate the damage that an additional ton of carbon in the
atmosphere will do, not just this year but for a century or more to
come; and you also have to decide how much weight to place on harm that
will take a very long time to materialize.
The policy-ramp advocates argue that the damage done by an additional
ton of carbon in the atmosphere is fairly low at current concentrations;
the cost will not get really large until there is a lot more carbon
dioxide in the air, and that won’t happen until late this century. And
they argue that costs that far in the future should not have a large
influence on policy today. They point to market rates of return, which
indicate that investors place only a small weight on the gains or losses
they expect in the distant future, and argue that public policies,
including climate policies, should do the same.
The big-bang advocates argue that government should take a much longer
view than private investors. Stern, in particular, argues that policy
makers should give the same weight to future generations’ welfare as we
give to those now living. Moreover, the proponents of fast action hold
that the damage from emissions may be much larger than the policy-ramp
analyses suggest, either because global temperatures are more sensitive
to greenhouse-gas emissions than previously thought or because the
economic damage from a large rise in temperatures is much greater than
the guesstimates in the climate-ramp models.
As a professional economist, I find this debate painful. There are
smart, well-intentioned people on both sides — some of them, as it
happens, old friends and mentors of mine — and each side has scored some
major points. Unfortunately, we can’t just declare it an honorable draw,
because there’s a decision to be made.
Personally, I lean toward the big-bang view. Stern’s moral argument for
loving unborn generations as we love ourselves may be too strong, but
there’s a compelling case to be made that public policy should take a
much longer view than private markets. Even more important, the
policy-ramp prescriptions seem far too much like conducting a very risky
experiment with the whole planet. Nordhaus’s preferred policy, for
example, would stabilize the concentration of carbon dioxide in the
atmosphere at a level about twice its preindustrial average. In his
model, this would have only modest effects on global welfare; but how
confident can we be of that? How sure are we that this kind of change in
the environment would not lead to catastrophe? Not sure enough, I’d say,
particularly because, as noted above, climate modelers have sharply
raised their estimates of future warming in just the last couple of
years.
So what I end up with is basically Martin Weitzman’s argument: it’s the
nonnegligible probability of utter disaster that should dominate our
policy analysis. And that argues for aggressive moves to curb emissions,
soon.
The Political Atmosphere
As I’ve mentioned, the House has already passed Waxman-Markey, a fairly
strong bill aimed at reducing greenhouse-gas emissions. It’s not as
strong as what the big-bang advocates propose, but it appears to move
faster than the policy-ramp proposals. But the vote on Waxman-Markey,
which was taken last June, revealed a starkly divided Congress. Only 8
Republicans voted in favor of it, while 44 Democrats voted against. And
the odds are that it would not pass if it were brought up for a vote
today.
Prospects in the Senate, where it takes 60 votes to get most
legislation through, are even worse. A number of Democratic senators,
representing energy-producing and agricultural states, have come out
against cap and trade (modern American agriculture is strongly
energy-intensive). In the past, some Republican senators have supported
cap and trade. But with partisanship on the rise, most of them have been
changing their tune. The most striking about-face has come from John
McCain (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/people/m/john_mccain/in…
), who played a leading role in promoting cap and trade, introducing a
bill broadly similar to Waxman-Markey in 2003. Today McCain lambastes
the whole idea as “cap and tax,” to the dismay of former aides.
Oh, and a snowy winter on the East Coast of the U.S. has given climate
skeptics a field day, even though globally this has been one of the
warmest winters on record.
So the immediate prospects for climate action do not look promising,
despite an ongoing effort by three senators — John Kerry (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/people/k/john_kerry/ind…
), Joseph Lieberman (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/people/l/joseph_i_liebe…
) and Lindsey Graham (
http://topics.nytimes.com/top/reference/timestopics/people/g/lindsey_graham…
) — to come up with a compromise proposal. (They plan to introduce
legislation later this month.) Yet the issue isn’t going away. There’s a
pretty good chance that the record temperatures the world outside
Washington has seen so far this year will continue, depriving climate
skeptics of one of their main talking points. And in a more general
sense, given the twists and turns of American politics in recent years —
since 2005 the conventional wisdom has gone from permanent Republican
domination to permanent Democratic domination to God knows what — there
has to be a real chance that political support for action on climate
change will revive.
If it does, the economic analysis will be ready. We know how to limit
greenhouse-gas emissions. We have a good sense of the costs — and
they’re manageable. All we need now is the political will.
Paul Krugman is a Times columnist and winner of the 2008 Nobel Memorial
Prize in Economic Science. His latest book is “The Return of Depression
Economics and the Crisis of 2008.”
[View Less]
fyi, paul w.
---------- Forwarded message ----------
From: Public News Service <wvns(a)newsservice.org>
Date: Tue, Apr 13, 2010 at 4:03 AM
Subject: WVNS story: "Something Fishy" At Mine Where 29 Died
To: PaulWilson <pjgrunt(a)gmail.com>
Public News Service-WV
April 13, 2010
"Something Fishy" At Mine Where 29 Died
CHARLESTON, W.Va. -Federal mine safety officials say explosions like the one
that killed 29 West Virginia miners last week are completely preventable.
Such things …
[View More]shouldn't happen, they say. And congressman Nick Rahall, whose
district includes Montcoal, says the record at Massey Energy's Upper Big
Branch Coal Mine there smells.
"Doesn't take a rocket scientist to determine by looking at all the
violations that have been issued here that something was wrong, something
was fishy here. That's clear by the whole public record."
The Secretary-Treasurer of the West Virginia *AFL-CIO*, Larry Matheney, says
one problem is that miners don't complain about safety for fear of losing
their jobs.
"It's the economy and high unemployment, particularly in the coal fields;
miners' economic survival, their families versus personal safety, putting
their lives at risk."
Early indications suggest that methane built up in the mine and ignited. An
investigation by the Charleston Gazette suggests that parts of the mine
might have been shut down, except that Massey aggressively fought
regulators' efforts to close off unsafe areas. Massey contends those
violations had nothing to do with the accident.
Click here to view this story on the Public News Service RSS site and access
an audio version of this and other stories:
http://www.publicnewsservice.org/index.php?/content/article/13438-1<http://www.publicnewsservice.org/index.php?/content/article/13438-1>
---
To be removed from this list please send an e-mail to
remove(a)publicnewsservice.org
<remove(a)publicnewsservice.org?subject=remove>and put the word "remove"
in the subject line.
--
Paul Wilson
Sierra Club
504 Jefferson Ave
Charles Town, WV 25414-1130
Phone: 304-725-4360
Cell: 304-279-1361
"There is no forward until you have gone back" ~Buddha
"In all things of nature there is something of the marvelous" ~ Aristotle
[View Less]
April 7, 2010
NY Times Op-Ed Contributor
Mourning in the Mountains
By DENISE GIARDINA
Charleston, W.Va.
PEOPLE in West Virginia had hoped that on Monday night we would gather
around televisions with family and friends to watch our beloved Mountaineers
face Butler in our first chance at the men’s N.C.A.A. basketball title since
1959. Men working evening shifts in the coal mines would get to listen
thanks to radio coverage piped in from the surface. Expectations ran high;
even President Obama, …
[View More]surveying the Final Four, predicted West Virginia
would win.
Then, on Tuesday morning, we would wake to triumphant headlines in sports
pages across the country. At last, we would say, something good has happened
to West Virginia. The whole nation would see us in a new light. And we would
cry.
Instead, halfway through Saturday night’s semifinal against Duke, our star
forward, Da’Sean Butler, tore a ligament in his knee, and the Mountaineers
crumbled. And on Monday evening, while Duke and Butler played in what for us
was now merely a game, West Virginians gathered around televisions to
watch news
of a coal mine disaster<http://www.nytimes.com/2010/04/07/us/07westvirginia.html?ref=us>
.
On Tuesday, the headline in The Charleston Gazette read instead: Miners
Dead, Missing in Raleigh Explosion. And we cried.
Despite the sunny skies and unseasonably warm weather, the mood here in
southern West Virginia is subdued. As of Tuesday afternoon, 25 men have been
confirmed dead, two are critically injured, and four are missing and
presumed dead. Their fellow West Virginians work round the clock and risk
their own lives to retrieve the bodies.
Already outrage is focused on Massey Energy, owner of the Upper Big Branch
mine. Massey has a history of negligence, and Upper Big Branch has often
been cited in recent years for problems, including failure to properly vent
methane gas, which officials say might have been the cause of Monday’s
explosion.
It seems we can’t escape our heritage. I grew up in a coal camp in the
southern part of the state. Every day my school bus drove past a sign posted
by the local coal company keeping tally, like a basketball scoreboard, of
“man hours” lost to accidents. From time to time classmates whose fathers
had been killed or maimed would disappear, their families gone elsewhere to
seek work.
We knew then, and know now, that we are a national sacrifice area. We mine
coal despite the danger to miners, the damage to the environment and the
monomaniacal control of an industry that keeps economic diversity from
flourishing here. We do it because America says it needs the coal we
provide.
West Virginians get little thanks in return. Our miners have historically
received little protection, and our politicians remain subservient to Big
Coal. Meanwhile, West Virginia is either ignored by the rest of the nation
or is the butt of jokes about ignorant hillbillies.
Here in West Virginia we will forget our fleeting dream of basketball glory
and get about the business of mourning. It is, after all, something we do
very well. In the area around the Upper Big Branch, families of the dead
will gather in churches and their neighbors will come to pray with them.
They will go home, and the same neighbors will show up bearing platters of
fried chicken and potato salad and cakes. The funeral homes will be jammed,
the mourners in their best suits and ties and Sunday dresses.
And perhaps this time President Obama and Americans will pay attention, and
notice West Virginia at last.
Denise Giardina is the writer-in-residence at West Virginia State
University.
--
Paul Wilson
Sierra Club
504 Jefferson Ave
Charles Town, WV 25414-1130
Phone: 304-725-4360
Cell: 304-279-1361
"There is no forward until you have gone back" ~Buddha
"In all things of nature there is something of the marvelous" ~ Aristotle
[View Less]
Anybody interested?
Jim Sconyers
jim_scon(a)yahoo.com
304.698.9628
Remember: Mother Nature bats last.
--- On Thu, 4/8/10, Scott Elkins <scott.elkins(a)sierraclub.org> wrote:
From: Scott Elkins <scott.elkins(a)sierraclub.org>
Subject: Last minute request
To: "'Jim Sconyers'" <jim_scon(a)yahoo.com>
Date: Thursday, April 8, 2010, 3:51 PM
Jim:
This is last minute, but I’m wondering if you can identify
2-4 chapter folks from …
[View More]West Virginia who would
be interested in attending the Good Jobs, Green Jobs Conference in
Washington DC ,
May 4-6. The Club can cover travel and lodging costs for up to four chapter folks
from West Virginia ,
but the trick is that we need to get the folks identified and signed up by Monday,
April 19th. Also, we want the folks to be willing to commit to three
things at and after the event:
• Participate in the conference Advocacy Day on May 6,
spending a full day participating in meetings with
U.S. Representatives and Senators
to discuss green jobs.
• Expand our on-the-ground relationships with labor, by recording your
existing labor contacts on the conference registration form and, by using the
conference as a networking opportunity, expanding your local connections.
• Post-GJGJ Collaboration: Commit to pursuing one or more follow up
initiatives or activities with your local contacts, and to report on them in a
follow-up survey, approximately two months after the conference.
If you can identify some folks in
West Virginia who are game for this, please have
them sign up at this web address http://spreadsheets.google.com/viewform?formkey=dGxjUThyWDJ5M0FfMXZiRUNRamo….
After they sign up, one of our staff in DC will get in touch with them about arranging
travel and hotel.
If you can help out with this, Jim, I’d appreciate it.
If you’re too busy but know of someone else in the chapter who may be able
to help recruit for this, that would be great too.
Thanks,
Scott
Scott Elkins
Director for Chapter Coordination - Climate Recovery
Campaign
Sierra Club
2327 E Franklin
Ave
Minneapolis
MN 55406
tel. 612-659-9124
fax 612-659-9129
cell 612-720-0793
[View Less]
fyi, in case you don't get the Washington comPost. paul
---------- Forwarded message ----------
From: Bruce Hamilton <Bruce.Hamilton(a)sierraclub.org>
Date: Tue, Apr 6, 2010 at 2:14 PM
Subject: Fw: WaPo: Massey Energy has litany of critics, violations
To: pjgrunt(a)gmail.com
----- Forwarded by Bruce Hamilton/Sierraclub on 04/06/2010 11:14 AM -----
From: Josh Dorner/Sierraclub
To: #Coal, #Media, #conservation-carbon
Date: 04/06/2010 11:07 AM
Subject: WaPo: …
[View More]Massey Energy has litany of critics, violations
------------------------------
We are of course still confining any public comments to our concerns about
the miners and their families; however, it hasn't taken reporters too long
to uncover all of Massey's problems--including more than 50 safety
violations *last month* at the mine where the accident occurred.
*Massey Energy has litany of critics, violations*
By Steven Mufson
Washington Post Staff Writer
Tuesday, April 6, 2010; 1:47 PM
*Massey Energy*<http://financial.washingtonpost.com/custom/wpost/html-qcn.asp?dispnav=busin…>,
owner of the coal mine where at least *25 miners died this
week*<http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2010/04/05/AR201004050…>,
and its outspoken chief executive, Don Blankenship, have long been lightning
rods for critics of the coal industry.
And although the company says that its safety record is better than the
industry average, Massey has frequently been cited for safety violations,
including about 50 citations at the Upper Big Branch mine in March alone.
Many of those 50 citations were for poor ventilation of dust and methane,
failure to maintain proper escape ways, and the accumulation of combustible
materials.
The U.S. Mine Safety and Health Administration cited the mine for 1,342
safety violations from 2005 through Monday for a total of $1.89 million in
proposed fines, according to federal records. The company has contested 422
of those violations, totaling $742,830 in proposed penalties, according to
federal officials.
Blankenship has called congressional Democrats seeking climate change
legislation "greeniacs" and "all crazy." He's said, "I don't believe that
climate change is real," and that House Speaker Nancy Pelosi (D-Calif.) and
Senate Majority Leader Harry M. Reid (D-Nev.) "don't know what they're
talking about." And in a video promoting a Labor Day music and political
event last year, he said, "We're going to have Hank Williams and a very good
time, but we're also going to learn how environmental extremists and
corporate America are both trying to destroy your job."
He has also thrown his weight around West Virginia, shelling out more than
$3 million of his own money for ads to help defeat a West Virginia state
Supreme Court justice. Blankenship expected the justice to rule against
Massey in an appeal of a $50 million award for a small coal company owner,
who convinced a jury that Massey had driven his company into bankruptcy. The
new judge cast the deciding vote against the $50 million award. The U.S.
Supreme Court later ruled that the new judge should have recused himself.
As a director of the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, Blankenship has helped
buttress the chamber's tough position against a climate change bill that
many other corporate members support. In November, he donated $30,400 to the
National Republican Senatorial Committee.
Blankenship is also a longtime foe of unions, earning the enmity of union
leaders. The mine where the accident took place Monday is a nonunion mine.
Although environmental groups have been working to stop the construction of
new coal-fired power plants in order to stop the increase in greenhouse
gases, coal continues to play a major role in the nation's energy picture. A
little less than half of electricity in the United States is generated by
coal-fired plants. And coal is also used by much of U.S. industry for power
needs.
News of the mine disaster pummeled the stock of Massey, the nation's fourth
largest coal company. At 1:30 p.m., the company's stock was down more than
10 percent, erasing more than $400 million of market value. Massey, which is
headquartered in Richmond, has operations in West Virginia, Kentucky and
Virginia and is the largest coal producer in Central Appalachia.
The company boasts on its *Web site* <http://www.masseyenergyco.com/> that
it has a good safety record compared with the rest of the industry. "In
2009, Massey recorded an all-time best NFDL incident rate (a measure of
lost-time accidents) of 1.67," the site says. "This is an improvement over
last year's rate of 1.93, our previous best result. By comparison, the
bituminous coal mining industry average NFDL rate was 2.95 in 2008. 2009
marked the 6th consecutive year and the 17th year out of the past 20 years
in which Massey's safety performance was stronger than the industry
average."
But the company had a litany of violations just last month at the Upper Big
Branch mine, according to the U.S. Mine Safety and Health Administration Web
site. In March, U.S. Mine Safety and Health Administration officials cited
the mine, which is owned by Massey subsidiary Performance Coal Co., for
failing to control dust; improperly planning to ventilate the mine of dust
and the combustible gas methane; inadequate protection from roof falls;
failing to maintain proper escapeways; and allowing the accumulation of
combustible materials."
Mining companies are permitted to contest violations and proposed penalties
and safety violations are not placed on a company's permanent safety record
until a dispute is settled, officials said. The 2006 MINER Act in the wake
of the 2006 Sago Mine disaster bolstered the agency's inspection staff and
increased penalties for safety violations. The change in law has led to a
higher number of citations and penalties and more challenges by companies,
federal mine safety officials said.
The Associated Press reports that "in seven of the last 10 years, the mine
has recorded a non-fatal injury rate worse than the national average for
similar operations, according to MSHA statistics. One miner was killed at
the operation in a July 2003 electrical accident and another in a March 2001
roof fall, according to MSHA records."
Blankenship has a *Twitter feed* <http://twitter.com/DonBlankenship>, but he
has not written anything about the accident and has not updated the feed in
the past week. On March 26, he posted a link to a list of senators who he
said "support higher taxes, higher electric bills and fewer American jobs."
Earlier that day, he wrote: "New study in Geophysical Research Letters finds
strong winds cause ice loss in Arctic Those full of hot air like Gore should
avoid the Arctic."
*Staff reporter Ed O'Keefe and research director Lucy Shackelford
contributed to this report.*
-----------------
Josh Dorner
Sierra Club
tel 202.675.2384
cel 202.679.7570
--
Paul Wilson
Sierra Club
504 Jefferson Ave
Charles Town, WV 25414-1130
Phone: 304-725-4360
Cell: 304-279-1361
"There is no forward until you have gone back" ~Buddha
"In all things of nature there is something of the marvelous" ~ Aristotle
[View Less]
fyi, paul
---------- Forwarded message ----------
From: Elena Saxonhouse <Elena.Saxonhouse(a)sierraclub.org>
Date: Tue, Apr 6, 2010 at 12:54 PM
Subject: Fw: Agenda for April 22-23 EIPC Stakeholder meeting
To: CONS-ELP-TRANS-LINES-FORUM(a)lists.sierraclub.org
----- Forwarded by Elena Saxonhouse/Sierraclub on 04/06/2010 09:54 AM -----
From: <eipconline(a)keystone.org>
To: <eipconline(a)keystone.org>
Date: 04/06/2010 09:46 AM
Subject: Agenda for …
[View More]April 22-23 EIPC Stakeholder meeting
Sent by: eipclist-bounces(a)keystone.org
------------------------------
[image: Text Box: Comments on the EIPC straw proposal for the Stakeholder
Steering Committee (SSC) and the agenda for the Eastern Interconnection-wide
stakeholder meeting on Thurs. and Fri., April 22-23, in St. Louis, Missouri
have been posted at http://eipconline.com/document_library.php. To attend
the meeting you must register by April 14th, by completing the information
at: http://www.zoomerang.com/Survey/WEB22AE6SFFYEB. All attendees must make
their own travel arrangements. The information about the hotel and room
block is provided when you register (and there is no confirmation email, so
please print out the page when you complete the survey). We strongly
encourage everyone to attend in person and to send individuals who can speak
on behalf of their organization. Decisions about the structure and selection
process for the SSC will be made at this meeting. Stakeholders who cannot
attend will have remote access to the meeting through a webinar link to the
plenary sessions and a conference call number for discussions that occur in
breakout sessions. These will be sent out in a future email. If you have
further questions about the meeting logistics or would like to unsubscribe
from this list, please contact Eileen at Emiller(a)keystone.org. Other
questions should be directed to dwhiteley(a)eipconline.com or
cmorris(a)keystone.org.]
_______________________________________________
EIPClist mailing list
EIPClist(a)keystone.org
http://keystone.org/mailman/listinfo/eipclist_keystone.org
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - To
unsubscribe from the CONS-ELP-TRANS-LINES-FORUM list, send any message to:
CONS-ELP-TRANS-LINES-FORUM-signoff-request(a)LISTS.SIERRACLUB.ORG Check out
our Listserv Lists support site for more information:
http://www.sierraclub.org/lists/faq.asp To view the Sierra Club List Terms &
Conditions, see: http://www.sierraclub.org/lists/terms.asp
--
Paul Wilson
Sierra Club
504 Jefferson Ave
Charles Town, WV 25414-1130
Phone: 304-725-4360
Cell: 304-279-1361
"There is no forward until you have gone back" ~Buddha
"In all things of nature there is something of the marvelous" ~ Aristotle
[View Less]